Jun 12, 2014 12:00
slavery,
india,
alanturing,
independence,
rape,
charity,
scotland,
women,
phones,
hbo,
movies,
transparency,
usa,
ipv4,
raykurzweil,
humans,
london,
bodies,
rome,
austerity,
nuclearweapons,
transport,
military,
self-defence,
taxi,
research,
minesweeper,
links,
drugs,
history,
uk,
europe,
ai,
funny,
firefox,
guns,
davidcameron,
censorship,
neilgaiman,
maps,
internet,
tv,
gameofthrones,
jkrowling,
rats,
viajamesnicoll,
fish,
ipv6,
evolution,
warnerbrothers,
amazon,
politics
I think it’s lessened by using preferential systems but I’d need to think about the mechanics of that.
But the example above is a bit of a narrow case. If I, for example, shift the vote in all of the homogenous regions very slightly, so that A has 201 votes and D 99 (rather than 199 and 101) then A wins 18 seats, rather than 9 (45% rather than 22.5%) and D wins 2 seats rather than 11 (5% rather than 27.5%)
(Using S-L everyone still wins 10 seats each or 25%).
Unsurprisingly, if you use a whole of d’Hondtland consitutuency the results are much more proportional, with A and B winning 13 seats (32.5%) and C and D winning 7 seats (17.5%) on vote shares of 31.8%, 31.3%, 18.7% and 18.2%. (No change using S-L).
So the choice is the classic choice about features of electoral systems. You can have more (or less) proportionality, or more (or less) community links to MP’s or more (or less) stable results but you can’t have everything. (Which many non-voting nerds seem not to believe or insist that eveyone ought to value the strengths and weaknesses of electoral systems as they do.)
Reply
Reply
Reply
I was so convinced as well... didn't see that factor without working it all through.
My apologies.
Reply
Reply
Reply
Reply
Reply
Reply
Reply
Reply
Leave a comment